Macro economic school header

The Keynesian School of Economics

The Keynesian School of Economics focuses on government spending to control the economy. Keynesian economists believe a troubled economy will continue downward unless an intervention drives consumers to buy more goods and services. In fact, they try to prevent all recessions from deepening into depression.

The Keynesian Economic School of Thought

The Keynesian Revolution: Economic Theory in Crisis and Recovery

In the tumultuous aftermath of the 1929 stock market crash, a profound intellectual vacuum emerged in economic theory as global economies plunged into unprecedented decline. Traditional economic frameworks, built on assumptions of self-correcting markets, proved woefully inadequate in explaining—much less resolving—the catastrophic economic conditions unfolding worldwide. From this theoretical void emerged John Maynard Keynes, a brilliant economist whose revolutionary ideas would fundamentally transform our understanding of economic depressions and establish the foundations of modern macroeconomics.

The Intellectual Breakthrough: Understanding Aggregate Demand

Keynes’s most significant contribution was his radical reconceptualization of economic downturns. While classical economists insisted that markets would naturally rebalance, Keynes made a giant leap forward for evolutionary economics. Keynes identified a fundamental flaw in this reasoning. He recognized that the core problem driving the Great Depression was not market inefficiency but a collapse in aggregate demand—the combined total spending by consumers, businesses, and governments throughout an economy.

This insight was revolutionary. Keynes demonstrated how, during severe economic contractions, a devastating feedback loop emerges: initial declines in spending force businesses to reduce production and lay off workers, whose lost income further decreases spending power, triggering additional layoffs and production cuts in a spiraling contraction. The economy thus reaches a new equilibrium, characterized by mass unemployment and industrial stagnation rather than full productive capacity.

Perhaps most brilliantly, Keynes identified the “paradox of thrift.” During economic crises, actions that appear rational for individual economic actors—consumers saving rather than spending, businesses postponing investments until conditions improve—collectively deepen the crisis when adopted simultaneously across the economy. What serves individual prudence becomes a collective catastrophe, as the economy settles into a persistent depression.

The Investment Conundrum: A Structural Contradiction

Keynes’s analysis of private investment behavior during depressions revealed another critical insight. Regardless of available resources or potential profitability, businesses rationally defer new investments until they observe tangible evidence of broader economic recovery. Yet this recovery fundamentally depends on the very investments that companies are postponing. As each investor waits for others to move first, a structural impasse develops where investment, the lifeblood of economic growth, grinds to a halt.

This paradoxical situation—where collectively beneficial action becomes individually irrational—forms the theoretical foundation for Keynes’s most controversial proposition: the necessity of government intervention in economic affairs. Classical economic theory had long maintained that free markets would naturally self-correct without external interference. Keynes demonstrated why this assumption fails during severe downturns.

The Case for Government Intervention

Keynes systematically analyzed the potential sources of economic stimulus during a depression and found only three possibilities:

1. Increased consumer spending (practically impossible during periods of high unemployment and financial insecurity)

2. Renewed business investment (stalled by the investment conundrum described above)

3. Government expenditure funded through borrowed or created money1

With the first two options effectively neutralized during depression, Keynes argued that only the government possessed the resources and the motivation necessary to break the deadlock. Governments could inject purchasing power directly into the economy by initiating large-scale public works and employment programs, creating the initial demand to justify private investment and restarting the economic engine.

This proposition represented a revolutionary break from economic orthodoxy. Rather than seeing government spending as competitive with or harmful to private enterprise, Keynes reframed it as the essential catalyst needed to revive private sector activity during severe contractions. The multiplier effect would then amplify initial government expenditures as they circulated through the economy, generating far more economic activity than the original stimulus.

From Theory to Policy: The Global Legacy

Though initially controversial, Keynesian principles eventually became the worldwide cornerstone of modern economic management. The theoretical frameworks Keynes developed now underpin central banking practices globally, even in nations ideologically opposed to his broader political philosophy. This widespread adoption reflects not ideological conversion but pragmatic recognition of the theory’s effectiveness in managing economic cycles.

Today, Keynesian principles are so thoroughly integrated into central bankers’ toolkits and policy that advanced economies seldom experience recessions. When GDP contractions occur, massive deficit spending facilitated by Keynesian frameworks functions as a buffer against deeper economic collapse. However, it is “impossible to ‘time’ the market”—to identify precise tops or bottoms. Therefore, Keynesian buffers are intended to ward off depressions but tend to eliminate recessions. Using the logic from the Austrian school, this only serves to create liquidity bubbles, prolonging the fundamental issue of overinvestment in the center or a technological cycle.

Limitations and Critiques

Despite its transformative influence, Keynesian theory is not without mainstream macroeconomic criticisms. The original framework struggled to explain why aggregate demand would suddenly collapse in the first place in the center of the technology cycle. Instead, such collapses should be treated as exogenous shocks rather than inherent features of market economies. This skirts the 800-pound gorilla in the room, which is the technology cycles themselves. Critics also note that widespread implementation of Keynesian policies didn’t occur until economies had begun recovering independently after 1932, complicating claims about their historical effectiveness.

Moreover, when Keynes developed his logic, Carlota Perez had not yet modified Schumpeter’s or Kondratiev’s technology cycle models. In other words, while Keynes correctly identified fiscal stimulus as necessary when depressions occur, his framework didn’t fully address the underlying cyclical patterns in technological innovation and deployment that might trigger such downturns. He didn’t know why they occurred and did not address those complex factors. There is far more to it than stimulus.

The Great Recession: Keynesian Theory in Modern Crisis

The 2007-2008 financial crisis and subsequent Great Recession offered a modern laboratory for testing Keynesian principles. Perspectives from leading economists reveal both the strengths and limitations of the Keynesian approach in contemporary contexts. Quotes from various economists reveal an ongoing struggle to adapt Keynesian principles to general modern realities, specifically technology cycles.2

Nobel laureate George Akerlof, for instance, expressed satisfaction with how mainstream economics had “successfully advised politicians to bail out the banking system” and thus “avoided the great depression as in the 1930s.” In his view, this “finger in the dyke” policy represented a Keynesian success story. However, as Joseph Stiglitz pointedly observed, this “success” must be weighed against “the ensuing unemployment, the collapse in investment, and GDP [that] caused a sharp reduction in living standards.” The critical question remains: “Just who did Bernanke save the banking system for?” 3

Paul Krugman, a prominent contemporary Keynesian, characterizes economic crises as fundamentally technical problems rather than systemic failures. “The problem is not with the economic engine, which is as powerful as ever,” he argues. “Instead, we are talking about what a technical problem is. A problem of organization and coordination.” Following Keynes, he attributes downturns primarily to “hoarding money” that creates demand shortfalls, requiring government intervention to break the “liquidity trap.”

However, this perspective may oversimplify complex structural issues. As the source material notes, Krugman’s analysis assumes saving occurs across society, when in reality, “the GM-CC \[presumably the group most capable of saving] was only the upper 20%, which could save more. Most middle-class people live paycheck to paycheck, with less than $50k in assets. This is a one-factor perspective.”4

Inequality and Financial Instability: Post-Keynesian Perspectives

Post-Keynesian economists have extended Keynes’s framework to incorporate factors he didn’t fully address, particularly the role of inequality and financial deregulation in creating economic instability. James Galbraith argues that “As Wall Street rose to dominate the U.S. economy, income and pay inequalities in America came to dance to the tune of the credit cycle,” positioning the rise of the finance sector as the driving force linking inequality to economic instability.5

Joseph Stiglitz takes a similar position, noting that growing income inequality has redirected money “from those who would spend it to those well off,” who, “try as they might, they can’t spend it all.” This concentration of wealth creates a “flood of liquidity” that ultimately “contributed to the reckless leverage and risk-taking that underlay this crisis.” Stiglitz attributed the shock to the “switch from manufacturing to a service sector.6

Economist Emmanuel Saez’s research supports these perspectives, demonstrating that nations making “significant cuts in top tax rates, such as the UK and the US, have not grown significantly faster” than countries maintaining higher taxation. Instead, “we have seen decades of increasing income concentration that have brought about mediocre growth since the 1970s.”7

Post-Keynesian economist Engelbert Stockhammer synthesizes these insights, arguing that “the economic imbalances that caused the Great Recession are the effects of financial deregulation and the macroeconomic effects of rising income inequality.” His analysis highlights how “rising inequality creates a downward pressure on aggregate demand since poorer income groups have high marginal propensities to consume,” while simultaneously leading to “higher household debt” as “working-class families have tried to keep up despite stagnating or falling real wages.”8

Keynesian Economics: A Complex Legacy

Keynes’s revolutionary insights remain foundational to modern economic theory and policy, offering crucial frameworks for understanding and addressing economic downturns. His identification of aggregate demand failures, the paradox of thrift, and the investment conundrum provided essential tools for managing economic cycles that have helped prevent depressions on the scale of the 1930s.

Yet contemporary economic challenges reveal the strengths and limitations of pure Keynesian approaches. While direct government stimulus remains a powerful tool for counteracting economic contractions, a more comprehensive understanding must incorporate insights about technological cycles, financial regulation, and income distribution that Keynes’s original framework didn’t fully address.

As economies face new challenges—from technological disruption to climate change to pandemics—Keynes’s central insight remains relevant: markets alone cannot always self-correct. Sometimes, collective action through government policy becomes necessary to restore economic balance. However, the form this intervention should take continues to evolve as our understanding of economic complexities deepens beyond what even Keynes himself could have envisioned.

The legacy of Keynesian economics is not simply a fixed set of policy prescriptions but a dynamic intellectual framework that continues to evolve as economists grapple with new economic realities. In this ongoing evolution lies the enduring value and the necessary limitations of Keynes’s revolutionary contribution to economic thought.

A Few More Quotes

Ben Bernanke

Since one unit’s liability is another units asset, changes in leverage represent no more than a redistribution. From one group (debtors) to another (creditors)… and should have no significant macroeconomic effects.9

Larry Summers

Larry Summers was a former Treasury secretary under President Bill Clinton. Back in 2005, at the Fed’s summer school, economist Raghuram Rajan presented a paper. He argued that the freeing up of regulations on the financial sector was a recipe for trouble. It would create a credit bubble that would burst. Summers quickly condemned Rajan as a “Luddite.”.10 There was no need for restrictions on the new financial innovations, later delightfully called “financial instruments of mass destruction” by Warren Buffett. For Summers, these new instruments brought “substantially more stability” to financial markets.11

There is a lot I don’t know about the economy. I have devoted most of my energy and attention to the ups and downs of the business cycle. This is where I often find myself. Confronting important questions without obvious answers.” (Greg Mankiw is a Harvard University economics professor).12

Paul Krugman

Are wars the only way to implement big government spending? According to Krugman, “the answer, unfortunately, is yes. Big spending programs rarely happen except in response to war or the threat.” It’s war Keynesianism or nothing.13 Sadly, the Marxists would be the only other macroeconomic school to agree. The last macroeconomic school is the Marxist school. That is the final stop in the review of the four major macroeconomic schools.

The last school is the Marxist school of thought

For additional background on general economic theory for the four schools you can visit wikipedia. It is not perfect but at least is not incented to be biased.

  1. FIAT currency ↩︎
  2. The Long Depression. How it happened, Why it happened, and What happens next. Author Michael Roberts. Haymarket Books, 2016. It misses the mark. It was written in 2016 when the Great Recession looked like it would never bottom. Sadly, the result seen today resulted from the complete lack of policy changes in response to the Great Recession. The book is chock-full of great quotes showing economists decrying what to do. ↩︎
  3. IBID page 77 ↩︎
  4. IBID page 79 ↩︎
  5. IBID page 86 ↩︎
  6. IBID page 86 ↩︎
  7. IBID page 87 ↩︎
  8. IBID page 89 ↩︎
  9. IBID page 91. ↩︎
  10. A Luddite was a name for British hand weavers during the Industrial Revolution. The Luddites smashed up the new machines that were replacing them. ↩︎
  11. The Long Depression. How it happened, Why it happened, and What happens next. Author Michael Roberts. Haymarket Books 2016. Page 71. ↩︎
  12. IBID Page 74 ↩︎
  13. IBID Page 80 ↩︎