
The Monetarist Economic School of Thought
The Supply-Side Perspective
The Monetarist School of Economic Thought, primarily associated with Nobel laureate Milton Friedman, represents one of the most influential perspectives in modern macroeconomics. Emerging as a counterpoint to Keynesian economics in the mid-20th century, monetarism places monetary policy at the center of economic analysis and prescription. This school of thought gained prominence through its interpretation of the Great Depression, arguing that what transformed a routine recession into history’s most devastating economic collapse was fundamentally a failure of monetary policy rather than an inherent flaw in the capitalist system itself.
Core Principles of Monetarism
At its foundation, monetarism rests on several key principles that differentiate it from other economic schools of thought:
1. Money supply primacy: Monetarists believe that changes in the money supply are the most significant determinants of economic activity.
2. Monetary rule: Monetarists advocate for steady, predictable growth in the money supply rather than discretionary policy.
3. Natural rate hypothesis: The economy tends toward a “natural” unemployment rate and output in the long run, regardless of monetary policy.
4. Rational expectations: Economic agents make decisions based on all available information, including anticipated policy actions.
5. Limited government intervention: Generally, monetarists favor minimal government involvement in markets beyond maintaining monetary stability.
The Monetarist Interpretation of the Great Depression
The cornerstone of monetarist analysis of the Great Depression centers on the Federal Reserve’s policies between 1929 and 1933. Monetarists, led by Friedman, argued that monetary contraction, poor decision-making by the Federal Reserve System, and a prolonged crisis in the banking sector primarily caused the Depression.
According to this view, the Federal Reserve committed a critical error by allowing the money supply to contract by approximately one-third during the first four years of the Depression. In Friedman’s assessment, had the Fed intervened appropriately, what became the Great Depression would have remained “just another recession.” This perspective fundamentally challenges narratives that attribute the Depression to inherent instabilities in capitalist production or market failures.
Friedman specifically highlighted how the Fed’s inaction during significant bank failures produced widespread panic and triggered runs on local banks throughout the financial system. The argument suggests that timely emergency lending to key financial institutions would have prevented the cascading collapse of smaller banks, thereby preserving the money supply. Without this intervention, businesses found themselves unable to secure new financing or renew existing loans, leading to a severe contraction in investment activity.
Money Supply Contraction as the Primary Culprit
The monetarist explanation emphasizes that a deflationary spiral took hold as the money supply rapidly contracted. With fewer dollars in circulation:
– Prices fell across the economy – Existing debt became more burdensome in real terms – Consumer spending decreased – Business investment plummeted – Unemployment soared
This process created a self-reinforcing cycle where each element exacerbated the others, driving the economy deeper into depression. According to monetarists, this cycle could have been interrupted through proper monetary intervention, specifically by ensuring that the money supply remained stable or expanded slightly rather than contracting dramatically.
Irving Fisher’s Debt-Deflation Theory
While not strictly a monetarist, Irving Fisher’s debt-deflation theory complements monetarist explanations of the Great Depression. Fisher, a leading economist of the era, identified over-indebtedness and deflation as the predominant factors driving the economic collapse.
Fisher traced the origins of the crisis to loose credit policies that fueled speculation and asset bubbles. A prime example was the stock market, where margin requirements were astonishingly low—investors could purchase stocks with just a 10% down payment, borrowing the remaining 90% from brokers. When market prices collapsed in 1929, brokers issued margin calls that borrowers couldn’t meet.
The debt-deflation theory outlines a circular process where:
1. Debt liquidation leads to distress selling
2. Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off
3. A fall in asset prices
4. A greater reduction in the net worth of businesses
5. A fall in profits
6. Reduction in output, trade, and employment
7. Pessimism and loss of confidence
8. Hoarding and further slowing of the velocity of circulation
9. Further deflation and debt liquidation
This process creates a paradoxical situation where collective attempts to reduce debt increase the real debt burden due to falling prices—the more debtors pay, the more they effectively owe in real terms. Fisher’s framework helps explain how monetary factors interacted with debt dynamics to transform a recession into the Great Depression.
The Banking Crisis Snowball Effect
As the crisis unfolded, bank failures became both a symptom and an accelerant of economic deterioration. Between 1930 and 1933, approximately 9,000 banks failed in the United States, freezing roughly $7 billion in deposits (equivalent to hundreds of billions in today’s dollars).
The banking collapse created a destructive feedback loop:
– Failing banks called in loans to improve liquidity
– Borrowers, already struggling with falling income, couldn’t repay
– More banks failed as loan defaults mounted
– Surviving banks became ultra-conservative, building reserves rather than lending
– Credit availability plummeted further
– Business investment and construction ceased
– Unemployment increased as businesses contracted
– Consumer spending fell further
– More businesses failed, leading to more bank failures
This vicious cycle intensified deflationary pressures throughout the economy. The monetarist perspective emphasizes that decisive intervention by the Federal Reserve to support banking liquidity could have interrupted this destructive pattern before it gained momentum.
Challenging the Banking Crisis Narrative
Not all economists accept the primacy of banking failures in explaining the Great Depression. Some evidence suggests that significant economic deterioration was already underway before the banking system collapsed.
Bank consolidation had been occurring throughout the 1920s, with the number of banks declining by more than 3% annually in the three years preceding 1929. Between 1929 and 1930, bank assets increased by 2.7%, indicating that the banking system initially remained relatively stable despite the market crash.
More significantly, industrial production had contracted dramatically—by almost 50%—between mid-1929 and mid-1930, while unemployment tripled from 2.9% to 8.9%. These indicators suggest the real economy was already in severe decline before the major banking crisis began in late 1930.
This timeline challenges the strictly monetarist interpretation by suggesting that other factors beyond monetary policy may have initiated the economic collapse, even if monetary contraction subsequently deepened the crisis.
Limitations of the Monetarist Explanation
While monetarism provides valuable insights into the Great Depression, its single-factor explanation has several limitations:
Complex Causality
The monetarist focus on money supply as the primary causal factor may oversimplify the complex web of economic, social, and political forces that contributed to the Great Depression. Factors such as wealth inequality, international trade policies, agricultural distress, and technological change all played significant roles that cannot be reduced to monetary dynamics alone.
Technological Cycles
The monetarist framework struggles to account for how technological innovation cycles influence economic activity. Major depressions often coincide with transitions between technological paradigms, suggesting structural factors beyond monetary policy may be at work in triggering economic crises.
International Dimensions
The global nature of the Great Depression, affecting economies with diverse monetary systems and policies, suggests that factors beyond any single nation’s monetary policy were at play. The gold standard’s international constraints, trade barriers, and war debts created interdependencies that monetarist models do not fully incorporate.
Policy Implementation Challenges
Even if monetary contraction was the primary cause, the monetarist prescription faces practical implementation challenges. During severe crises, traditional monetary transmission mechanisms may break down as banks hoard reserves regardless of central bank actions—a phenomenon economists call the “liquidity trap.”
The Efficient Markets Hypothesis and Its Limitations
Eugene Fama, a Chicago School economist closely aligned with monetarist thinking, developed the Efficient Markets Hypothesis, which posits that financial markets incorporate all available information into prices. This theory suggests that markets, when free from interference, should produce optimal outcomes and stable growth.
However, when confronted about the 2008 financial crisis, Fama’s response was telling: “We don’t know what causes recessions… We have never known. Debates go on to this day about what caused the Great Depression.” This admission reveals a significant blind spot in monetarist and neoclassical frameworks—they struggle to explain why severe economic downturns occur at all in supposedly efficient markets.
Fama’s assertion that “if I could have predicted the crisis, I would have” highlights a circular logic: if markets are efficient, crises shouldn’t happen; if crises happen, they must have been unpredictable; therefore, markets remain efficient despite crises. This reasoning insulates the theory from falsification but limits its practical utility in understanding economic instability.
Contemporary Relevance and Policy Implications
The monetarist interpretation of the Great Depression continues to influence modern central banking practices. Ben Bernanke, a scholar of the Great Depression before becoming Federal Reserve Chairman, explicitly applied monetarist lessons during the 2008 financial crisis, ensuring aggressive liquidity provision to prevent banking system collapse. However, most contemporary central banks employ hybrid approaches rather than purely monetarist frameworks. The Federal Reserve, European Central Bank, and other major monetary authorities now consider multiple economic indicators beyond money supply, including:
– Employment levels, Output gaps, Inflation expectations, Financial market conditions, Credit availability, & International capital flows
This pragmatic evolution recognizes both the insights and limitations of monetarist theory. While maintaining price stability remains a central objective, policymakers increasingly acknowledge that monetary policy alone cannot ensure economic stability.
Conclusion: Monetarist Schools
The monetarist interpretation of the Great Depression provides crucial insights into how monetary contraction can deepen economic crises. Friedman’s work permanently altered how economists and policymakers understand the role of central banks during financial panics. The lesson that central banks must act decisively as lenders of last resort during banking crises represents a lasting contribution to economic thought.
However, as the complexity of understanding technology cycles grows, purely monetarist explanations appear increasingly insufficient. Economic cycle modeling requires a broader toolkit than monetary policy alone can provide. The limitations of the monetarist model have led many economists and policymakers toward synthesis approaches that incorporate insights from multiple macroeconomic schools of thought. However, none of the macroeconomic schools can account for the dynamics of technology cycles, the outlines of which are becoming almost impossible to overlook.
The most common model used today by central bankers worldwide is the Keynesian model. We are headed there next.
The next school is Keynesian economics
For additional background on general economic theory for the four schools you can visit wikipedia. It is not perfect but at least is not incented to be biased.